“TO tax and to please, no more than to love and be wise, is not given to men,” said the great Whig statesman, Edmund Burke. The aphorism requires qualification today because Burke lived long before the invention of corporation tax. In 2016, at least in theory, it is possible to tax companies while simultaneously pleasing voters — those who are incensed by the tax avoidance efforts of multinationals shocked by market rigging and violation of anti-money laundering rules by big banks, enraged at the size of bankers’ bonuses and worried about extremes of inequality.

Yet, despite successful raids on the coffers of the banks, governments have had limited success in extracting more tax revenue from the wider corporate sector of the developed world. And public attitudes to tax in general are complex — witness the apparent lack of appetite for re-distributive taxation to address inequality despite the fact that economists at the International Monetary Fund have found that redistribution and reduced inequality support faster and more durable growth .

In short, something interesting is happening to the political economy of taxation.

Consider, first, the remarkable profitability of the global corporate sector. On the basis of data from 28,000 companies, a recent study by the McKinsey Global Institute shows corporate earnings be­fore taxes and interest more than tripled from $2tn in 1980 to $7.2tn in 2013, rising from 7.6pc of world gross domestic product to almost 10pc. Importantly, corporate net earnings after taxes and interest rose even more sharply.


Economists at the International Monetary Fund have found that redistribution and reduced inequality support faster and more durable growth


As well as the opening up of emerging markets, the boom in post-tax earnings reflects such factors as falls in borrowing costs and the price of labour, equipment and technology — and falling corporate tax rates. In part, falling tax rates reflect competition between states for internationally mobile investments. Yet corporate tax revenues are also under pressure because national tax laws have been left behind by the movement of global capital and the fact that corporate assets are increasingly intangible.

Multinationals thus structure their activities to exploit the gaps and mismatches in the system. Through the perfectly legal shifting of profits to low or no-tax locations, such companies undermine the fairness and integrity of tax systems around the world. Economists at the OECD estimate the resulting annual losses incurred by governments at anywhere from four to 10pc of global corporate income tax revenues, or $100bn to $240bn annually. This is most conspicuously true of American multinationals, which keep more than $2tn of earnings abroad in order to avoid paying US tax.

The pressure of public opinion has caused some large corporations to temper the aggressiveness of their avoidance plans. And now the base erosion and profit shifting initiative — run jointly by the OECD and the Group of 20 leading nations — is seeking to plug tax gaps and loopholes. Yet this is soft law, and no G20 government appears ready for more radical solutions, such as taxing corporate income at the jurisdiction where the sales occur, as with value added tax. Also, the money power that big business deploys via campaign finance and intensive lobbying saps political will for higher corporate taxes.

On the wider issue of inequality and redistribution, on both sides of the Atlantic the public appears to have accepted the post-Reagan, post-Thatcher orthodoxy that imposing higher taxes on the rich and increasing aid to the poor is bad for economic growth, notwithstanding the work of IMF economists referred to earlier. In addition, because the financial crisis was not followed by a 1930s-style slump, the redistributive impulse that led to the New Deal is absent today.

There has also been a longer-term retreat from the belief that a just society requires its winners to provide a safety net to the less well-off. This emerges particularly strongly from the British Social Attitudes surveys, which chart a collapse in support for welfare spending from 65pc in 1991 to 31pc in 2010. There has been a 20 to 30-year decline in the preference for redistribution and a decline in trust in the ability of governments to use tax revenues efficiently.

Now evidence has emerged, in a recent Brookings Institution paper by William Gale, Melissa Kearney and Peter Orszag, that increasing the top marginal tax rates for those in the 95th percentile and upwards has only a trivial effect on overall income inequality.

Regardless of public opinion, this new fiscal climate is relatively kind to corporations. And the Anglo-American public feels less kind towards society’s losers.

john.plender@ft.com

Published in Dawn, Business & Finance weekly, January 11th, 2016

Follow Dawn Business on Twitter, LinkedIn, Instagram and Facebook for insights on business, finance and tech from Pakistan and across the world.

Opinion

Editorial

Taxing pensions
Updated 11 May, 2024

Taxing pensions

Tax reforms have failed to deliver because of distortions created by the FBR bureaucracy through SROs, apparently for personal gains.
Orwellian slide
11 May, 2024

Orwellian slide

IN recent years, Pakistan has made several attempts at introducing an overarching mechanism through which to check...
Terror against girls
11 May, 2024

Terror against girls

ONCE again, the ogre of terrorism is seeking the sacrifice of schoolgirls. On Wednesday, just days after the...
Enrolment drive
Updated 10 May, 2024

Enrolment drive

The authorities should implement targeted interventions to bring out-of-school children, especially girls, into the educational system.
Gwadar outrage
10 May, 2024

Gwadar outrage

JUST two days after the president, while on a visit to Balochistan, discussed the need for a political dialogue to...
Save the witness
10 May, 2024

Save the witness

THE old affliction of failed enforcement has rendered another law lifeless. Enacted over a decade ago, the Sindh...