MY first graduate microeconomics class didn’t start with any grand theories or mathematical proofs. It started with a demonstration. The professor marched us down to a computer lab, divided us into groups of six, and had us participate in a simulated market.

Amazingly, the price of the virtual commodity we were trading quickly converged to a single value and stayed there. This was a powerful demonstration of the so-called law of one price, the economic principle that markets produce a single price for a given commodity or good.

Many sellers would love to change that law if they could. If merchants could raise prices for customers who were willing to pay more, they could make a lot more profit. Suppose there are two potential customers for my product — one who would buy it for $100 and another who would be willing to pay $150.

If I have to charge them both the same price, I’ll charge $100, so that I can sell two units and make $200. The second customer, who would have been willing to pay a higher price, ends up getting a bargain. In economics lingo, that bargain is called a consumer surplus.

Web use can give retailers clues about which customers to charge more

But if I could charge each a different price, I’d charge the first customer $100 and the second one $150, for a total of $250. In this case, the second customer wouldn’t get a bargain. That’s called price discrimination.

Merchants already do a fair amount of price discrimination. A car dealer will try to figure out how much you’re willing to pay by talking to you while you take a test drive, and try to persuade you to pay more.

Movie theatres offer discounts to seniors and students — people who are likely to have less money — while charging higher prices for working-age adults. The examples are many and ingenious. But there are limits on these shenanigans. When prices are posted publicly, as with a price tag at a store, everyone sees what everyone else is paying. That makes it a lot harder to charge different prices to different customers.

But in the age of the internet, the price-tag system becomes a lot more tenuous. Shopping online, it’s only me and my computer. When I see a posted price, I tend to assume others are seeing the same, but is that really true?

Blogger James Plunkett has a good rundown of recent evidence on this question. Various online retailers are occasionally caught charging different prices to different customers, including Amazon.com, which said it abandoned the practice in 2000. Researchers found in 2014 that human shoppers got worse bargains on a number of websites, compared to an automated browser that didn’t reveal its identity.

There are a bunch of ways companies can figure out how much each consumer is willing and able to pay. Some are easy — charge more to people using an expensive Apple computer, or to people using certain types of email accounts. An online retailer can also look at people’s product search histories to steer them toward higher-priced products.

This kind of price discrimination, based on income, isn’t very harmful to society — it can even be good, since it involves charging poor people less and allows them to buy things they otherwise couldn’t afford.

But the real money would come from big data. The more data a merchant gets about a customer — where they live, what they buy, what websites they visit, etc. — the better they can predict how much they’d be willing to pay for a certain product. Conceivably, with enough data, merchants could figure out the maximum amount each customer is willing to pay, and then charge them that.

If all merchants did this — which seems more likely in a world dominated by a few big players like Amazon — then competition wouldn’t result in prices being driven down. No shopper would ever get a bargain. It wouldn’t matter that poor people would potentially be able to buy more things; merchants might charge them so much that they’re not really any better off. And price discrimination is especially bad when combined with monopoly power — if large, dominant online retailers get into differential pricing, consumers could suffer a great deal.

As technology advances, regulation will need to keep up. Regular randomised experiments should be used to test large online retailers for evidence of personalised pricing. The government should allow price discrimination based on broad income classes — like giving discounts to seniors or students. But if big companies are caught trying to use big data to act like car dealers and squeeze customers for every last penny, they should be punished accordingly. Bloomberg/The Washington Post Service

Published in Dawn, The Business and Finance Weekly, March 19th, 2018

Opinion

Four hundred seats?

Four hundred seats?

The mix of divisive cultural politics and grow­th-oriented economics that feeds Hindu middle-class ambition and provides targeted welfare are key ingredients in the BJP’s political trajectory.

Editorial

Weathering the storm
Updated 29 Apr, 2024

Weathering the storm

Let 2024 be the year when we all proactively ensure that our communities are safeguarded and that the future is secure against the inevitable next storm.
Afghan repatriation
29 Apr, 2024

Afghan repatriation

COMPARED to the roughshod manner in which the caretaker set-up dealt with the issue, the elected government seems a...
Trying harder
29 Apr, 2024

Trying harder

IT is a relief that Pakistan managed to salvage some pride. Pakistan had taken the lead, then fell behind before...
Return to the helm
Updated 28 Apr, 2024

Return to the helm

With Nawaz Sharif as PML-N president, will we see more grievances being aired?
Unvaxxed & vulnerable
Updated 28 Apr, 2024

Unvaxxed & vulnerable

Even deadly mosquito-borne illnesses like dengue and malaria have vaccines, but they are virtually unheard of in Pakistan.
Gaza’s hell
Updated 28 Apr, 2024

Gaza’s hell

Perhaps Western ‘statesmen’ may moderate their policies if a significant percentage of voters punish them at the ballot box.