What governments do and why

Published Aug 27, 2013 07:48am

A SEMINAL book of the 20th century, at least for academics, was An Economic Theory of Democracy, published in 1957. In it, Anthony Downs applied economic theory to the study of politics and, among other things, inferred what a rational government would do given its incentives.

At its simplest, the theory claims that a government aims to stay in power and therefore, if it is democratic, adapts its policies and actions to appeal to a majority of the electorate.

For example, in the current run-up to the elections in India, the general wisdom is that the ruling party would spend extensively in the rural areas to negate a likely swing to the opposition in urban areas. (Contrary to Downs’ prototype, though, it seems it is not the effectiveness of expenditures that matters most to voter sentiment in India — it is the courting that is important.)

Incentives are the key variable in Downs’ proposition and in normal circumstances a government’s incentives are aligned with the objective of retaining power.

Having observed Pakistani politics for decades, however, a circle of friends has inferred a variation that might better explain outcomes in the country. It might also illustrate the nature of the gulf that has opened up between the politics of India and Pakistan.

The essence of the variation is that the incentive of a typical Pakistani civil government (as a whole, not of rogue individuals within it which is more universal) has not been re-election but the maximum accumulation of wealth during any period in which it is in office.

For one, the duration of its rule in any given period was highly uncertain given that real power was wielded behind the scene by actors other than itself. Therefore a strategy to satisfy the wants of any part of the electorate might yield no returns whatsoever.

For another, it knew, given the paucity of political alternatives, that in the merry-go-round of Pakistani politics its turn would eventually come again. Thus it made strategic sense to build up a war chest to sustain it during its period in the wilderness and be available when re-entry appeared possible.

This strategy was abetted by globalisation when virtually all Pakistani leaders arranged safe havens abroad to recuperate in when out of power or to which to escape when things got hot. Some are foreign nationals ruling by proxy from abroad; others shift abodes as and when the situation demands.

One consequence of the safe havens was that the leaders parked all their capital assets abroad and retained just running expenses in local currency.

The operating game plan was then entirely tactical and risk-free — to do whatever was needed to extend their resource-extracting rule in the short term till such time when the music stopped. At that moment, they could take flight literally with the clothes on their backs and await some patron or the other to engineer their return.

With such incentives there was little need or time to do anything for the electorate barring the incidental by-products of the process of making money (large infrastructure or service contracts, for example).

This was quite unlike India where electoral strategy demanded the amelioration of some constituency at the very least. Governments could guess wrong (as with the Shining India strategy) but none could afford to ignore all the constituents all the time.

The complete apathy towards citizen needs in Pakistan is plausible in this perspective. A victim is the democratic process itself. Unlike in India, the real opposition is no longer represented by alternate political parties but increasingly by groups that reject the worldview of electoral politics altogether.

The rejection also removes compunctions about the destructive economic consequences of their actions. They can survive on the bare minimum and believe everyone should too till the desired alternative is attained from which the nation would rise purer and stronger.

In exploring the fundamental divide in the politics of India and Pakistan, I often think back to the 300 years of the Mughal Empire. Half this period was dominated by the six Great Mughals whom everyone recognises. The other half was populated by dozens of emperors most of whom few can recall. This was the period dominated by behind-the-scene king-makers who shuffled puppet emperors at will, retaining them only for the legitimacy they conferred.

This could explain how democratic India and Pakistan both remain overwhelmingly dynastic and yet on different political trajectories. I am tempted to conclude that Indian politics is a continuation of the first half of the Mughal Empire while Pakistani politics resembles more the second — the rule of kings versus that of king-makers.

Of course, in the age of democracy kings don’t rule till they die or are deposed — they can take turns in office. From the viewpoint of incentives it makes a huge behavioral difference if a leader knows he has to remain at home when out of power as opposed to one prepared to flee abroad to seek a patron.

These contrasting imperatives, incentives, and strategies have led to divergent political trajectories in Pakistan and India and thereby to the different fate of their citizens — the one ignored, the other appeased.

The first completion of the political term of a civilian government in Pakistan could signal a change. Constraining further the power of king-makers could bend the Pakistani trajectory towards the Indian model, itself a variant of the Downs’ prototype.

When that happens, Pakistani citizens would attain parity with their Indian peers. It would make little difference in their immediate conditions, but place them on a better political platform for the long struggle ahead.

The writer is dean of the School of Humanities and Social Sciences at the Lahore University of Management Sciences.


Do you have information you wish to share with Dawn.com? You can email our News Desk to share news tips, reports and general feedback. You can also email the Blog Desk if you have an opinion or narrative to share, or reach out to the Special Projects Desk to send us your Photos, or Videos.

More From This Section

Nov 3: still a raw wound

There is no explanation given for why the majority judges thought it would be unjust to order a reinvestigation.

Debatable quota

Should military officers, even if retired, be part of the diplomatic corps?

Comments (4) Closed




khanm
Aug 27, 2013 04:38pm

The best argument about rational or irrational government is a five minutes conversation with an average voter

IndianInUS
Aug 27, 2013 08:02pm

Very nice article!! Good even by Machiavellian standards and I don't mean that in a bad way.

BRR
Aug 28, 2013 01:08am

Rather a good comparative analysis. Frankly the common man has little say in both places, but collectively, there is more room for change in India under the current circumstances, and different ethnic and social groups get their hands on the lever of power and pelf over time.

Zubia
Aug 28, 2013 02:36am

Thank you Anjum for an excellent analysis of our rulers and their behaviours. I must admit what you have written should have been obvious, but it required someone of your calibre to describe it for us to understand what we were seeing but failing to see. What needs to be done now is to bring this behaviour on the radar of the average voter. Just as the idea that a politician should not have a second nationality is now mainstream, maybe we need to now focus on that fact that if the politician went abroad when he was out of power should render him/her ineligible to stand for elections.