Warnings from Japan for the eurozone

Published November 10, 2014
Luxembourg’s Finance Minister Pierre Gramegna, left, speaks with EU Commissioner for the Economy Pierre Moscovici during a meeting of the eurogroup finance ministers in Brussels. Luxembourg came under pressure Thursday for allegations it has offered excessively sweet taxation deals to many multinationals and wealthy families that prefer to seek financial shelter in the Grand Duchy rather than pay higher taxes in other countries.—AP
Luxembourg’s Finance Minister Pierre Gramegna, left, speaks with EU Commissioner for the Economy Pierre Moscovici during a meeting of the eurogroup finance ministers in Brussels. Luxembourg came under pressure Thursday for allegations it has offered excessively sweet taxation deals to many multinationals and wealthy families that prefer to seek financial shelter in the Grand Duchy rather than pay higher taxes in other countries.—AP

Japan is no longer governed by consensus. This is true at least of its monetary policy. Haruhiko Kuroda, governor of the Bank of Japan, launched still greater ‘quantitative and qualitative monetary easing’ last week, with the backing of only five of the nine members of the Monetary Policy Committee.

The BoJ plans to purchase Japanese government bonds at an annual rate of Y80tn ($705bn), or 16pc of gross domestic product. The balance sheet of the central bank is set to jump towards 80pc of GDP (see chart). This would make the BoJ’s balance sheet relatively far bigger than those of the US Federal Reserve, European Central Bank and the Bank of England. In addition, the BoJ plans to lengthen the maturity of its asset purchases to between seven and 10 years.

The government pension investment fund has also announced that it will reduce its holdings of domestic bonds from 60pc of its portfolio to 35pc, while increasing its equity holdings (domestic and foreign) from 24 to 50pc. As a result, it will increase its holdings of Japanese equities by $90bn and of non-Japanese equities by $110bn. Indirectly, the BoJ is financing this by buying JGBs owned by the GPIF.

To justify its decision, the BoJ stated: “On the price front, somewhat weak developments in demand following the consumption tax hike [in April] and a substantial decline in crude oil prices have been exerting downward pressure.” As a result, it argues, there is a risk that ‘conversion of deflationary mindset, which has so far been progressing steadily, might be delayed’.


The reform should include increased taxation of retained corporate earnings


So will this reinforced attempt to end Japan’s entrenched deflation work? To answer, one needs to distinguish the direct effects from the signalling.

The purchases of equities by the GPIF might be significant. But it is hard to believe replacing JGBs with money in private portfolios would make much difference. Central-bank money can also be thought of as non-interest-bearing, irredeemable government debt. But 10-year JGBs yield less than 0.5pc. So the difference between the two forms of government ‘debt’ is tiny, particularly since the BoJ intends to reverse its monetary expansion at some point.

This makes the signalling the main channel. The decision is intended to underline the seriousness of the BoJ. But the split in the MPC must undermine the effectiveness of the signal it seeks to give and so weaken its impact.

The BoJ is combating the consequences of a bad policy error that it, alas, supported. The decision to raise the consumption tax this year was mistaken: it was mistimed, since it was introduced before the desired shift in inflationary expectations to an annual rate of 2pc had been entrenched; it was a tax on private consumption, of which Japan has too little, instead of on private savings, of which it has too much; and it did not address the structural cause of the latter, which is the chronic financial surplus of the corporate sector (the excess of its gross earnings over investment).

Since Japan’s bubble economy collapsed in the early 1990s, the private sector has run a huge financial surplus, which has been the counterpart of the government’s deficit and the net export of capital.. Today, nearly all that surplus is generated within the corporate sector. The government will be able to eliminate its own deficit, while avoiding a return to economic depression, if and only if spending rises elsewhere relative to incomes. A jump in net exports would be one possibility. A rise in investment would be another. A shift of income from corporations to households, and a rise in consumption by the latter, would be a third.

Could the BoJ’s monetary policy deliver such outcomes? Only up to a point. Negative real interest rates might permanently raise wasteful corporate investment. Negative real interest rates should also depreciate the exchange rate and so raise the current account surplus. Last week’s BoJ announcement weakened the yen by 4pc against the dollar between October 30 and November 4. Yet none of these shifts would directly tackle the structural problem in the corporate sector. Monetary policy would be no more than a palliative. Tax reform is needed — but the reform should include increased taxation of retained earnings rather than the government’s proposed reduction.

An alternative monetary policy does exist: direct financing of fiscal deficits by the central bank (also known as ‘helicopter money’). This would not eliminate the economic imbalances but would finance their consequences in the most direct way. Given Japan’s public debt overhang, however, such direct monetary financing of the government risks triggering an uncontrollable shift in expectations towards high inflation.

So what lessons should others, particularly the European Central Bank, learn from Japan’s predicament? The answer is: do not start from there.

The Japanese are where they are for three reasons. First, the Bank of Japan pursued too tight a monetary policy, especially in the early 1990s, to punish the sins of the bubble economy. Second, the government added too rapid a tightening of fiscal policy in 1997. Finally, the Japanese never dealt with structural excess savings in the corporate sector. These mistakes entrenched the disinflationary pressure that the BoJ now seeks to end with its desperate expedients.

All this has strong echoes today in the eurozone. Not least, the dominant attitudes are needlessly punitive. The eurozone has also been unwilling to address the structural excess savings of creditor countries. Yet what the eurozone should remember is that, regardless of economic outcomes, Japan will remain a functioning country with an utterly loyal citizenry. The eurozone does not possess such powerful advantages. It cannot even risk falling into anything close to Japanese deflation. But it is.

martin.wolf@ft.com

Published in Dawn, Economic & Business, November 10th, 2014

Follow Dawn Business on Twitter, LinkedIn, Instagram and Facebook for insights on business, finance and tech from Pakistan and across the world.

Opinion

Editorial

Digital growth
Updated 25 Apr, 2024

Digital growth

Democratising digital development will catalyse a rapid, if not immediate, improvement in human development indicators for the underserved segments of the Pakistani citizenry.
Nikah rights
25 Apr, 2024

Nikah rights

THE Supreme Court recently delivered a judgement championing the rights of women within a marriage. The ruling...
Campus crackdowns
25 Apr, 2024

Campus crackdowns

WHILE most Western governments have either been gladly facilitating Israel’s genocidal war in Gaza, or meekly...
Ties with Tehran
Updated 24 Apr, 2024

Ties with Tehran

Tomorrow, if ties between Washington and Beijing nosedive, and the US asks Pakistan to reconsider CPEC, will we comply?
Working together
24 Apr, 2024

Working together

PAKISTAN’S democracy seems adrift, and no one understands this better than our politicians. The system has gone...
Farmers’ anxiety
24 Apr, 2024

Farmers’ anxiety

WHEAT prices in Punjab have plummeted far below the minimum support price owing to a bumper harvest, reckless...